Full description not available
D**D
Original insights that are still relevant to urban growth and development
Most people know Jane Jacobs as the best representative of the movement to save cities from cars. She was seen as the main opponent to Robert Moses's attempt to turn Manhattan into a (bigger) parking lot. By trade, Jacobs was a journalist, but she made her mark with The Death and Life of Great American Cities (1961), a masterpiece of urban sociology that generations of car-obsessed planners have ignored at their peril. In that book, Jacobs draws on experience of living in New York and common sense as she explains the ways that people build social bonds with strangers and neighbors, and how those bonds create the "social fabric" that defines vibrant, resilient and prosperous neighborhoods (more on bonding).For a long time, I though these significant contributions to be the totality of Jacobs's work, but I was wrong -- in the most pleasant way, it turns out, as she wrote many other books. Her last, Dark Age Ahead (2007) was an early, and quite accurate, warning against the rise of illiberal forces. I enjoyed it immensely and turned to her for more to read.The Economy of Cities (1969) appealed to me not just because of the topic, but also its vintage, as I was born in that year. The book turns out to be another excellent read, mostly because it brings Jacobs's original perspective to an important topic: how do cities grow and develop?Before I move on, let me make a short note about this book's relative obscurity. Although I am hardly an expert of urbanism or urban economics, I would have expected to hear more about the ideas Jacobs discusses in this book, but it seems that those ideas have now become so firmly entrenched that they are no longer credited to her.*And Jacobs herself was not the first to talk about the economies of cities. Adam Smith was probably also not the first, but his 1776 characterization of economies of scope and scale has stood the test of time:As it is the power of exchanging that gives occasion to the division of labour, so the extent of this division must always be limited by the extent of that power, or, in other words, by the extent of the market. When the market is very small, no person can have any encouragement to dedicate himself entirely to one employment, for want of the power to exchange all that surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his own consumption, for such parts of the produce of other men's labour as he has occasion for.There are some sorts of industry, even of the lowest kind, which can be carried on no where but in a great town... [snip] In the lone houses and very small villages which are scattered about in so desert a country as the Highlands of Scotland, every farmer must be butcher, baker and brewer for his own family. In such situations we can scarce expect to find even a smith, a carpenter, or a mason, within less than twenty miles of another of the same trade... [snip]As by means of water-carriage a more extensive market is opened to every sort of industry than what land-carriage alone can afford it, so it is upon the sea-coast, and along the banks of navigable rivers, that industry of every kind naturally begins to subdivide and improve itself, and it is frequently not till a long time after that those improvements extend themselves to the inland parts of the country.Smith's observations on the size of the market more or less integrates an important element missing from basic economics, i.e., the importance of space and the transactions costs that arise with distance.** It is from this simple idea that Jacob's begins her book with her most controversial (?) idea, i.e., that cities predated agriculture and drove the agricultural revolution of 10,000 years ago.There's very little evidence and no written records to support this idea, but I find it far more plausible than the commonly held idea that farmers produced surpluses and thus enabled specialised trades and a bureaucratic class to arise. Against this series of steps, Jacobs supposes that "cities" -- basically villages whose specialized traders and craftsmen stayed put -- existed alongside hunter-gather societies, each playing a complementary role to the other. Given this start, Jacobs then makes the entirely plausible guess that specialization in handling animals would lead to breeding, and specialization in handling seeds and other foods would lead to the selection of those with higher yields or more attractive qualities, with such "innovations" then being exported from the villages back into the wilds -- and eventually the fields that would be defended by city-dwellers rich enough to build walls, hire guards and so on.This insight alone is worth reading the book, but there are more!One important implication of city-led innovation is that it rebukes governments that focus on rural development. Jacobs's advice would be "leave them alone to follow and learn from cities," but many governments subsidize, direct and protect rural areas in a crude attempt to develop them. Such strategy not only wastes resources and encourages corruption, it also retards urban and rural innovation. (Note that this pattern is not falsified by China's post-1980 rural-led development, as the Party would not have dared to give economic freedom to cities first.)Her next major point is that cities need to innovate if they are to survive. This means that "company towns" are likely only to last as long as their companies. In the book, she mentions how Detroit was a dynamo compared to Pittsburgh because it had so many industries to Pittsburgh's steel-dominated economy. With another 45 years of history, we now see how Detroit failed when its car industry stumbled, and Pittsburgh has "come back" through diversification. It's hard to remain king of the hill!Part of this thought that Jacobs spends some time on is the way that various players in supply chain must be competitive to service world-class firms, which means that they are also likely to be exporters, and thus the source of extra profits, jobs and prosperity. It is thus that Jacobs, with justification, highlights cities as the specialized engines increasing the Wealth of Nations. (Some might claim that countries can grown rich on agriculture, but the richest countries have stepped away from that sector.) She called this dynamic "import replacement" -- meaning that local firms would cut out distant suppliers to local producers/exporters. Her definition is realistic as the way cities grow and more realistic as a description of how to encourage than "import substitution," which depends on preventing foreign firms from supplying intermediate goods, in the hope that local firms would be able to fill the gap.*** The implication is that cities don't depend on ports or river access to grow, but a mix of older and younger industries that can export goods based on imported materials and innovate new goods and services as older enterprises decline.Finally (for now, but not the book), she looks into the future from 1969 to predict that cities would be able to mine their resources, a prediction decades ahead of modern pundits of industrial ecology and the circular economy. How would she get such an important insight? She saw cities as ecosystems rather than engineered or master-planned spaces beloved of the command and control crowd se fought for decades.Bottom line: I give this book FIVE STARS. Read it for the sheer pleasure of joining Jacobs on an exploration of how our urban economies evolve.For all my reviews, go here.* This contemporary review [pdf] notes her iconoclastic insights. This piece discusses how economists put her ideas ("Jacobs externalities") into play. Google scholar shows either 89 or 7000k+ citations of this book. I checked a few and she was not cited, so the algorithm is confused. I'd love to see a decent list of economists who have cited her.** In our daily lives, it's easy to see how urban sprawl and congestion increases the transaction costs of commuting and communicating with others in cities, which is why sprawl is bad for market efficiency and innovation. For some people, cars promise to "collapse space" but most of that promise has been lost in traffic jams caused by everyone else pursuing the same idea. It's that dynamic that underpins my claim that cities should be for people, not cars, a position of whose righteousness I experience every time I ride my bike through Amsterdam.*** Import substitution is often linked to failure and poverty in poorer countries. Import replacement is more effective but not the same as laissez-faire: countries can still use transition periods to gradually expose their local industries to stronger and/or subsidized competition from abroad.
B**R
Great understanding of how cities drive wealth creation
Having finished Rise and Decline, I knew I liked Jane Jacobs. Her clear writing style is on display here and she does a great job of making you question gut beliefs that may not have any basis in real life. Jacobs makes a convincing argument that cities rose up before agriculture and that cities today drive innovation, economic growth and national prosperity. We are smarter, more inventive and more dynamic when we live in cities, particularly the dynamic, walkable ones she describes in Rise and Decline. Excellent short read.
J**R
Great book!
Great book! As someone interested in entrepreneurship, especially in relationship to doing good for the community, this book gives a better idea of how cities actually work than most economic texts. This has given me a better framework for thinking of my local area, and my mind is whirring on places to insert myself (especially rethinking the various "breakaway" ideas I had at previous jobs!)
L**H
Great book for anyone wanting to understand urban growth & economics
Great book for anyone wanting to build a knowledge of urban economic theory. She's not an economist but comes to many of the same conclusions that urban economists do. I just attended the World Urban Forum in Malaysia and they offered a couple of workshops on Jane Jacobs. She's still relevant to understanding urban dynamics today.
A**H
Obviously you should read this after the Death and Life of Great American Cities
An interesting pro-urban thought experiment. Obviously you should read this after the Death and Life of Great American Cities. As fields of study go, too often urbanism is the first to fall victim to quantification to the detriment of theory. Without theory though, what we are left with are unspoken ideologies that bias our perspectives before we even begin to take measure. Jacobs was a rare voice that spoke positively of urbanism, and sought to analyze the city itself as a whole object, rather than just its component parts.
R**N
Cities push new technologies and interact with others to engage importing of more technologies.
I enjoyed the numerous examples of city success and failures. I had a hard time following some of the formulas.
F**K
Read this book and then read it again
Jane Jacobs is one of my personal heroes and this book is her manifesto. It's essential reading for anyone who wants to understand anyting about how cities work.
L**R
Best book on Economic Development ever written
The title of this book is slightly misleading, because the thesis of the book is that cities play an essential role in the process of economic development. Although its anecdotal style gives this book a disarmingly unsystematic appearance, this is a profound book. It is easily one of the most important books written during the 20th century. Economic development is something about which conventional marginal utility economics has very little to say. The Economy of Cities, therefore, fills a kind of void. It stands to conventional economics in much the same position as quantum physics stands to classical physics.A simply wonderful book.Lancelot Fletcher [email protected]
A**R
Growth of cities and innovation
Beautifully-written and thoughtful contesting the view that cities only arose after agricultural surpluses and instead pulled the surpluses. The main point is that cities are caldrons of innovation arising from import substitution and further divisions of labour, and ‘thick’ institutions. To some extent superseded by Castells and Hall’s emphasis on knowledge flows, more recently Sennett’s trilogy on cities emphasising relationalities as catalysing knowledge flows and all the stuff on inequalities in urban settings. Jacobs is almost entirely US-centres and pre-globalisation and pre-Asian development state and mega-cities, so again dated. All this said, a “must-read” on the theory of city growth, deeply thoughtful and challenging to old economics of agglomeration ideas.
A**P
Very good seller
Great book great condition
H**G
Un punto di vista alternativo sulla funzione economica delle città
C'è chi pensa alle città come parassiti che depredano la campagna, Jane Jacobs sostiene invece che le città sono il fondamentale motore economico, senza il quale la campagna stenterebbe persino a raggiungere l'autosufficienza. Immagino che la tesi sia osteggiata da molti economisti e altrettanti urbanisti, ma a me pare molto persuasiva.
M**S
Four Stars
fgreta book and good quality product for the price
A**R
Four Stars
Compact and concise enough
Trustpilot
1 month ago
1 week ago